Competition Mechanisms in the Sharing Economy
Małgorzata Godlewska
Abstract
In recent years, the sharing economy has experienced rapid growth across the globe in terms of the number of participants and transactions, as well as profits. Experts claim that the sharing economy offers new possibilities for entrepreneurship, reducing operating costs, creating new jobs, increasing the effectiveness of economic systems, giving better allocation of resources and assets, as well as increasing the competitiveness of numerous sectors and the quality of life for consumers.
The purpose of this article is to study the competition mechanisms utilized by online platforms operating in the sharing economy. Case studies were conducted on 20 leading online platforms operating in the main sectors of the sharing economy (e.g. transportation, tourism, finance, catering, education, leisure, animal care), which rendered it possible to identify 5 different competition mechanisms, ranging from aggressive, profit and economic advantage-oriented competitive pricing to pro-social, non-price competition based on non-profit activities, as well as offering social and epistemic advantage.
The main actors in the sharing economy apply various price and non-price competition mechanisms. Nevertheless, in practice, users are frequently "forced" by online platforms to compete for customers using pricing. This happens especially in situations where both the prices and the process of matching providers with recipients are regulated top-down by the platform. Online platforms frequently offer service providers no freedom in terms of decision-making. Moreover, online platforms, by using inflated and hardly credible ratings, render users unable to use non-price, reputation-based competition mechanisms, which, experts claim, may lead to the creation of a new form of precariat.
Keywords: sharing economy, competition mechanisms, two-sided markets, P2P, internet platforms
Introduction
The article is based on the results of the statutory study "Competition mechanisms in the 21st century", conducted under the supervision of Professor Jerzy Pietrewicz. The study was conducted by the author in 2018 at the Collegium of Business Administration of the Warsaw School of Economics. The purpose of this article was to identify the competition mechanisms utilized by the leading online platforms operating within the sharing economy based on a number of case studies (20 cases).
In recent years, the sharing economy has experienced rapid growth around the globe in terms of the number of participants and transactions, as well as profits. This has become possible due to the proliferation of the internet across the globe (Ericsson, 2015). The total value of transactions conducted in 2015 by EU member states ('EU') via online platforms in the main sectors of the sharing economy exceeded EUR 28 billion (European Parliament, 2017a).
Many experts, including Botsman and Rogers (2010), Allen and Berg (2014) and Sundararajan (2016), as well as institutions such as the European Parliament (2017b) and the European Commission (EC, 2016), claim that the sharing economy offers new possibilities in terms of: 1) growing entrepreneurship, 2) reducing operating costs, 3) creating new jobs, 4) increasing the effectiveness of economic systems, 5) more optimal resource and asset allocation, 6) increasing the competitiveness of many sectors of the economy, and 7) contributing to consumer prosperity. It is also important to note that, according to the European Parliament (2017b), the sharing economy is beneficial to EU society, even despite the challenges it poses to many traditional economic models. On the other hand, experts such as Slee (2015) and Toroń and Wiese (2017) note that the largest online platforms, such as UberX and Airbnb1, operate outside local and domestic legal frameworks. Moreover, the relevant literature poses questions regarding the economic and social implications of the sharing economy (Pietrewicz & Sobiecki, 2017, pp. 11-12) and the possibility of a paradigm shift from market capitalism to collaborative commons (Rifkin, 2016, pp. 9-35). In order to answer the above questions it is first necessary to determine the competition mechanisms utilized in the sharing economy. The purpose of this article was to identify the competition mechanisms utilized by online platforms operating within the sharing economy. Case studies were conducted for 20 leading online platforms operating in the main sectors of the sharing economy (e.g. transportation, tourism, finance, catering, education, leisure, animal care), which rendered it possible to identify five different competition mechanisms, ranging from aggressive, profit and advantage-oriented competitive pricing to pro-social, non-price competition based on non-profit activities, as well as acquiring a social and epistemic advantage.2The essence of the sharing economy
The sharing economy became the center of attention between 2011 and 2012 due to the success of two online platforms: Uber and Airbnb (Martin, 2016). The dynamic growth of the sharing economy which has taken place in the last 10 years, experts claim, has been caused by a change in the attitudes of consumers: 1) from the need to possess assets to the need to access them (Pietrewicz & Sobiecki, 2017), 2) from preferring full-time employment to flexible forms of work (Wosskow, 2014), 3) from private consumption to sharing what we possess with others (Belk, 2007), 4) from polluting the environment to reducing our environmental footprint (Schor, 2014), and 5) from extensive economic growth to sustained development (Heinrichs, 2013). Moreover, the neoclassical economic theory of sharing uses the example of club goods to emphasize that the sharing of private goods ceases the moment the costs of sharing such goods with another person exceed the benefits of sharing these costs (Buchanan, 1965, p. 5).
It is worth noting that the first attempt at defining the term sharing economy was made by Lessig (2008), who claimed that it constituted consumption via sharing, exchanging and lending one's own resources without transferring ownership rights. Botsman (2015) notes that the sharing economy should be understood to only encompass online platforms with clear values, operating based on transparent rules, which value and respect their users and offer them access to assets, not ownership of them, under more beneficial conditions compared to the traditional model. Frenken and Schor (2017) emphasize that the key aspect of the sharing economy is the less risky use of unallocated resources via sharing with strangers who can be rated.
The relevant literature (Slee, 2015; Einav, Farronato & Levin, 2015; Sundararajan, 2016) lists the following features shared by online platforms in the sharing economy, including Airbnb, UberX, EatWith, TaskRabbit and Getaround: 1) the ability to create new markets and challenge the leaders of the traditional economy, e.g. UberX challenging taxi corporations; 2) operating on two-sided markets, e.g. Airbnb is successful due to attracting a large number of both hosts (i.e. service providers) and guests, i.e. service beneficiaries; 3) utilizing network effects - e.g. dog owners (service beneficiaries) using Rover benefit from the increasing number of new dog walkers (service providers); 4) reaching users with the use of digital technologies, e.g. Getaround uses an application to find and open unused cars in the area; 5) use of mechanisms which match transaction parties, e.g. BlaBlaCar uses adverts posted on its online platform; 6) use of rating systems, e.g. TaskRabbit awards a special status to users with the highest ratings and who are the most active on the platform; and 7) cornering new markets, frequently by circumventing regulatory barriers.
It is worth noting that the sharing economy is primarily targeted at millennials living in urban areas who use the latest technologies, leaving the older generations and those living in rural areas outside its boundaries and sphere of influence (Wagner et al. 2015). Moreover, research conducted by the Center for a New American Dream (CNAD) demonstrates that 72% of all Americans participating in the sharing economy are motivated by purely financial reasons, not social ones (Fremstad, 2018). Mikołajewska-Zając and Rodak (2016, p. 68) underline that this "commodification of the sharing economy" may constitute the next stage of development of the market economy.
Competition mechanisms in the sharing economy
Effective competition mechanisms are crucial to global economic development (Śliwińska, 2013). Companies operating as part of the sharing economy compete with traditional market actors by using online-based business models. Online platforms provide the technologies necessary for transactions to take place between individual users (peer-to-peer, 'P2P') or businesses and individual users (business-to-peer, 'B2P'). Sharing economy entities compete in what are known as two-sided markets, and, in order to achieve success, they must acquire both service providers and recipients (Rochet & Tirole, 2003). Moreover, two-sided markets are characterized by the ability to expand rapidly and economies of scale (Demary, 2015). In addition, due to the network effect, the value of a service increases with the number of users, constituting a barrier to entry, which has affected certain Polish online platforms such as Wulu.pl, InOneCar.com and JadeZabiore.pl. The largest online platforms in the sharing economy profit from commissions charged for acting as an intermediary in transactions between service providers and recipients. Platforms such as Uber, Lyft, Getaround and Zipcar compete against one another and traditional market actors, striving to achieve analogous or similar goals, on occasion preventing their competitors from achieving their established targets3.
The competition mechanisms used by online platforms in the sharing economy are to a large degree determined by their market orientation and structure (Schor, 2014). An online platform may be profit-oriented or non-profit. The market structure adopted by the online platforms of the sharing economy is based on exchanges, leasing or sharing between participants (P2P) and/or exchanges between businesses and individual participants (B2P).
What is more, the credibility of an online platform and its users, as well as whether it possesses a relative competitive advantage (Kim, Yoon, & Zo, 2015) are also significant factors determining the competition mechanisms. The credibility of an online platform and its users can be built upon: 1) reputation via a rating system, e.g. Getaround; 2) free insurance, e.g. TaskRabbit and Airbnb; 3) social media presence (Facebook, Twitter, etc.), e.g. JustPark; and 4) posting comments, e.g. Airbnb. Moreover, rating systems used by online platforms, where ratings are based on comments and being active on the platform, are supposed to indicate the "digital quality" of platform users. Nonetheless, the European Parliament (2017a and 2017b) notes that online platforms may apply unfair and arbitrary practices with regard to publishing ratings and compiling user rankings based on those ratings. It should also be noted that a relative competitive advantage may be achieved by online platforms based on the following benefits (Kim, Yoon, & Zo, 2015): 1) economic benefits, e.g. rendering less expensive services than traditional businesses; 2) social benefits, e.g. potential new relationships; and 3) epistemic benefits, e.g. acquiring new experiences.
The analysis of 20 leading sharing economy platforms operating in the transportation, tourism, finance, catering, education, leisure and animal care sectors (see table 1) identified the following competition mechanisms:
- Aggressive price-based competition with ratings
Online platforms which utilize an aggressive price-based competition mechanism with ratings base their exclusively for-profit activities on offering an economic advantage. They compete with prices against one another and against traditional market actors. Transactions on such platforms occur between individual users (P2P). In addition, service providers on such platforms are rigorously assessed and rated by service recipients and the platform itself. Certain platforms (e.g. UberX) prevent service providers from creating their own pricing policies or selecting their "customers" (recipients) by use of sanctions (e.g. banning) for the "excessive" rejecting of jobs assigned by the platform. This mechanism is utilized by transportation platforms such as JustPark, UberX and Lyft. - Aggressive price-based competition without ratings
Online platforms utilizing this mechanism operate based on a strict for-profit model. In addition, they utilize economic and social advantages, competing with prices among themselves and against traditional market entities. Transactions on such platforms occur between businesses and individual users (B2P). Service providers on such platforms (businesses) are not rigorously assessed or rated by service recipients, as opposed to the rating model. This mechanism is utilized by food and grocery delivery, as well as office sharing platforms such as Postmates, WeWork and Instacart. - Moderate price-based competition
Online platforms utilizing the moderate price-based competition mechanism use both economic and non-economic (social and epistemic) advantages. They operate strictly for profit, but also undertake additional activities to enable their users to (at least in theory) meet new people and acquire new experiences. Such platforms compete with prices among themselves and against traditional market entities. Transactions occur between individual users (P2P). In addition, it is the service providers who are most frequently rated on platforms utilizing the above mechanism. This model is used by platforms offering meal and car sharing services such as EatWith and BlaBlaCar, as well as platforms acting as intermediaries in task delegation such as TaskRabbit and Handy. - Price-based competition with moderate non-price competition
Online platforms utilizing this combination of competition mechanisms operate based on an economic advantage and are strictly profit-oriented. They compete among each other and against traditional market actors using pricing and non-price factors, e.g. the experience and reputation of their service providers. Transactions on such platforms occur primarily between individual users (P2P). In addition, both the recipients and providers are assessed and rated. This model is utilized by platforms which offer car and sports equipment rental services such as Getaround and Spinlister, as well as platforms which act as intermediaries in renting out rooms and providing animal care services, such as Airbnb and Rover. - Pro-society, non-price competition
Online platforms utilizing the pro-society, non-price competition mechanism do not operate for profit, and focus primarily on non-economic advantages. They do not compete using prices against one another or traditional market actors. Transactions on such platforms occur between individual users (P2P). In addition, it is the recipients who are most frequently rated. This model is utilized by platforms which focus on non-profit activities, such as Kiva and Streetbank.
Name of online platform | Service | Competition mechanism (CM)4 | Type CM5 | Market structure | Market orientation6 | Rating system7 | Relative advantage8 |
JustPark | Renting of parking spots | PC | Aggressive PC with ratings | P2P | FP | P | E |
UberX and uberPOOL | Sharing of means of transport | PC | Aggressive PC with ratings | P2P | FP | P | E |
Lyft or Shared | Sharing of means of transport | PC | Aggressive PC with ratings | P2P | FP | P | E |
Postmates | Package delivery, e.g. food, groceries | PC | Aggressive PC without ratings | B2P | FP | None | E and S |
WeWork | Office space sharing | PC | Aggressive PC without ratings | B2P | FP | None | E and S |
Rent the Runway | Renting out clothes and accessories | PC | Aggressive PC without ratings | B2P | FP | None | E |
Instacart | Grocery deliveries | PC | Aggressive PC without ratings | B2P | FP | None | E and S |
TaskRabbit | Assigning tasks | PC | Moderate PC | P2P | FP | P | E and S |
Handy | Assigning tasks | PC | Moderate PC | P2P | FP | P | E and S |
EatWith | Meal sharing | PC | Moderate PC | P2P | FP | P | EP, E and S |
BlaBlaCar | Car sharing | PC | Moderate PC | P2P | FP | R and P | E and S |
Favor | Food deliveries | PC | Moderate PC | P2P | FP | None | E and S |
Getaround | Renting out unused cars | PC, NC | PC, moderate NC | P2P | FP | R and P | E |
Spinlister | Renting out high-end sports equipment | PC, NC | PC, moderate NC | P2P | FP | R and P | E |
Airbnb | Renting out unoccupied rooms, apartments and houses | PC, NC | PC, moderate NC | P2P, B2P | FP | R and P | E and S |
Rover (DogVacay) | Looking after dogs and cats | PC, NC | PC, moderate NC | P2P | FP | P | E |
Coursera | E-learning courses and specializations, post-graduate programs | PC, NC | PC, moderate NC | B2P | FP | None | E |
Kiva | Loans of between USD 25 and 700 for new businesses in developing countries | NC | Pro-society NC | P2P | NP | R | E and S |
Streetbank | Sharing tools with neighbors | NC | Pro-society NC | P2P | NP | None | E and S |
Couchsurfing | Couch sharing | NC | Pro-society NC | P2P | FP | R and P | EP, E and S |
Source: author's own work based on 20 case studies of the largest online platforms in the sharing economy.
The sharing economy allows both online platforms and users to apply various competition mechanisms. Despite the promises by the largest sharing economy platforms regarding applying social economy principles or ensuring a fair distribution of profits, price-based competition is pervasive in practice. Service providers on those platforms compete for customers (service recipients) primarily using pricing, not quality or experience. Only platforms such as Kiva, Streetbank and Couchsurfing do not force their service providers to apply price-based competition mechanisms. A possible explanation is that these platforms do not operate for profit (with the exception of Couchsurfing9). Many researchers believe that the price-based competition occurring between service providers on online platforms may lead to the formation of a new form of precariat (Standing, 2011). Moreover, research conducted by Slee (2015) and Zervas, Proserpio and Byers (2015), for example, confirms that the rating systems used by online platforms are inflated and inaccurate, as more than 98% of all service providers on platforms such as Airbnb, Handy (Homejoy) and TaskRabbit are rated higher than 4.7 (out of 5). Thus, service providers, instead of utilizing non-price competition mechanisms based on reputation, are forced to compete using prices. In addition, online platforms in the sharing economy do not allow users to transfer ratings between them, their stated reasons being that having a high rating as an Airbnb host, for example, is not comparable to a different activity, e.g. being an Uber driver. Nevertheless, users of online platforms such as Airbnb, Rover (DogVacay) and Getaround use non-price mechanisms in addition to price competition, emphasizing their experience or offering additional services. In addition, a case study on Airbnb has demonstrated that an "appropriate" photo of the host has an impact on the popularity of what they offer and whether or not they can demand a higher rate (Ert, Fleischer and Magen, 2016).
Summary
Online platforms operating in the sharing economy use various competition mechanisms, from aggressive, profit and economic advantage-oriented, price-based methods to pro-society, non-price mechanisms based on non-profit activities and social and epistemic advantages.
Nevertheless, in practice, users are frequently "forced" by online platforms to aggressively compete for customers using pricing. This happens especially in situations where both the prices and the processes of matching providers with customers are regulated in a top-down fashion by the platform. Online platforms such as Uber, Postmates and Instacart offer service providers no freedom in terms of decision-making.
Moreover, online platforms, by way of using inflated and hardly credible ratings (Slee, 2015), prevent users from applying non-price, reputation-based competition mechanisms. This phenomenon may lead to the formation of a new form of precariat (Standing, 2011). Nevertheless, users of online platforms such as Airbnb, Rover (DogVacay) and Getaround use non-price mechanisms in addition to price competition, emphasizing their experience or offering additional services. In addition, platforms such as Kiva and Streetbank, which are non-profit in nature, allow their users to use non-price mechanisms.
It is worth noting that, according to numerous researchers (e.g. Scott & Edda, 2014; Slee, 2015; Frenken & Schor, 2017), online platforms operating as part of the sharing economy frequently resort to unfair practices, as unlike traditional market actors, many regulations do not apply to them, enabling such companies to avoid certain costs by transferring them and their related risks to service providers, i.e. the users of these platforms, the majority of whom are natural persons (microenterprises).
References
- Allen, D., & Berg, C. (2014). The sharing economy. How over-regulation could destroy an economic revolution. Retrieved from https://collaborativeeconomy.com/wp/wp-content/uploads/2015/04/Allen-D.-and-Berg-C.2014.The-Sharing-Economy.-Institute-of-Public-Affairs.-.pdf
- Belk, R. (2007). Why not share rather than own? Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 611, 126-140. DOI: 10.1177/0002716206298483
- Botsman R. (2015). Defining The Sharing Economy: What Is Collaborative Consumption-And What Isn't?. Retrieved from https://www.fastcompany.com/3046119/defining-the-sharing-economy-what-is-collaborative-consumption-and-what-isnt
- Botsman, R., & Rogers, R. (2010). What's Mine Is Yours: The Rise of Collaborative Consumption. Harper Business Kindle Edition.
- Buchanan, J. (1965). An economic theory of clubs. Economica, 32(125), 1-14.
- Burgiel, A. (2015). Determinanty i perspektywy upowszechnienia konsumpcji wspólnej w Polsce. Studia Ekonomiczne. Zeszyty Naukowe Uniwersytetu Ekonomicznego w Katowicach, 231, 7-29.
- Corbin, J., & Strauss, A. (1990). Grounded Theory Research: Procedures, Canons and Evaluative Criteria. Qualitative Sociology, 13(1), 3-21.
- Demary, V. (2015). Competition in the Sharing Economy. Retrieved from https://www.iwkoeln.de/fileadmin/publikationen/2015/235445/Sharing_Economy_Policy_Paper.pdf
- Einav, L., Faronato, C., & Levin, J. (2015). Peer-to-Peer Markets. Annual Review of Economics, 8, 615-635. DOI: 10.1146/annurev-economics-080315-015334
- Ericsson. (2015). Ericsson Mobility Report on the pulse of the networked society. Retrieved from https://www.ericsson.com/assets/local/news/2015/6/ericsson-mobility-report-june-2015.pdf
- Ert, E., Fleischer, A., & Magen, N. (2016). Trust and reputation in the sharing economy: The role of personal photos in Airbnb. Tourism Management, 55, 62-73. DOI: 10.1016/j.tourman.2016.01.013
- European Commission. (2016). Komunikat Komisji do Parlamentu Europejskiego, Rady, Europejskiego Komitetu Ekonomiczno-Społecznego i Komitetu Regionów: Europejski program na rzecz gospodarki dzielenia się. Retrieved from https://ec.europa.eu/docsroom/documents/16881/attachments/2/translations/pl/renditions/native+&cd=1&hl=pl&ct=clnk&gl=pl
- European Commission. (2018). Common position of national authorities within the CPC Network on the commercial practices and the terms of service of Airbnb Ireland. Retrieved from https://ec.europa.eu/info/sites/info/files/final_common_position_on_airbnb_ireland_4.6.2018_en_002.pdf
- Fremstad, A. (2018). Is there a future for sharing? A comparison of traditional and new intitutions. Journal of Insitutional Economics, 14(4), 595-616. DOI: 10.1017/S1744137417000297
- Frenken, K., & Schor, J. (2017). Putting the sharing economy into perspective. Environmental Innovation and Societal Transitions, 23, 3-10. DOI: 10.1016/j.eist.2017.01.003
- Glaser, B., & Strauss, A. (1967). The Discovery of Grounded Theory: Strategies for Qualitative Research. Mill Valley, CA: Sociology Press.
- Heinrichs, H. (2013). Sharing Economy: A Potential New Pathway to Sustainability. Gaia - Ecological Perspectives for Science and Society, 22(4), 228-231.
- Kim, J., Yoon, Y., & Zo, H. (2015). Why people participate in the Sharing Economy: A Social Exchange Perspective. Journal of the Association for Information Science and Technology, 67(9), 2047-2059. DOI: 10.1002/asi.23552
- Konecki, K. T. (2018). Studia z metodologii badań jakościowych. Teoria ugruntowana. Warszawa: Wydawnictwo Naukowe PWN.
- Lessig, L. (2008). Remix: Making art and commerce thrive in the hybrid economy. New York: Penguin.
- Martin, C. J. (2016). The sharing economy: A pathway to sustainability or a nightmarish from neoliberal capitalism?. Ecological Economics, 121, 149-159. DOI: 10.1016/j.ecolecon.2015.11.027
- Meelen, T., & Frenken, K. (2015). Stop Saying Uber is Part of the Sharing Economy. What is being shared besides your money? Retrieved from https://www.fastcompany.com/3040863/stop-saying-uber-is-part-of-the-sharing-economy
- Mikołajewska-Zając, K., & Rodak, O. (2016). Platformy współdzielcze jako próba rewizji korporacyjnego modelu gospodarki współdzielonej. e-mentor, 4(66), 67-73. DOI: 10.15219/em66.1265
- European Parliament. (2017a). Gospodarka dzielenia się: Posłowie chcą unijnej strategii. Retrieved from http://www.europarl.europa.eu/news/pl/headlines/economy/20170428STO72971/gospodarka-dzielenia-sie-poslowie-chca-unijnej-strategii
- European Parliament. (2017b). Rezolucja Parlamentu Europejskiego z dnia 15 czerwca 2017 r. w sprawie europejskiego programu na rzecz gospodarki dzielenia się. Retrieved from http://www.europarl.europa.eu/sides/getDoc.do?pubRef=-//EP//TEXT+TA+P8-TA-2017-0271+0+DOC+XML+V0//PL
- Pietrewicz, J. W., & Sobiecki, R. (2017). Przedsiębiorczość Sharing Economy. In M. Poniatowska-Jaksch, & R. Sobiecki (Eds.). Sharing Economy (gospodarka współdzielenia) (pp. 11-26). Warszawa: Oficyna Wydawnicza SGH.
- Poniatowska-Jaksch, M., & Sobiecki, R. (Eds.). (2017). Sharing Economy (gospodarka współdzielenia). Warszawa: Oficyna Wydawnicza SGH.
- Rifkin, J. (2016). Społeczeństwo zerowych kosztów transakcyjnych. Internet przedmiotów, Ekonomia współdzielenia, Zmierzch kapitalizmu. Warszawa: Wydawnictwo Studio Emka.
- Rochet, J.-C., & Tirole, J. (2003). Platform Competition in Two-sided Markets. Journal of the European Economic Association, 1(4), 990-1029. DOI: https://doi.org/10.1162/154247603322493212
- Schor, J. (2014). Debating the Sharing Economy. Retrieved from https://www.greattransition.org/publication/debating-the-sharing-economy
- Scott, M., & Eddy, M. (2014). Uber Service Banned Across Germany by Frankfurt Court. Retrieved from http://bits.blogs.nytimes.com/2014/09/02/uber-banned-across-germany-by-frankfurt-court/?_php=true&_type=blogs&emc=eta1&_r=0
- Slee, T. (2015). What's yours is mine. Against the Sharing Economy. New York, London: OR Books.
- Śliwińska, M. (2013). Ochrona konkurencji we współczesnej gospodarce wyzwaniem dla teorii konkurencji. Ekonomia i Prawo, 13(2), 207-219. DOI: 10.12775/EiP.2013.016
- Standing, G. (2011). The precariat. London: Bloomsbury Academic.
- Stankiewicz, M. J. (2005). Konkurencyjność przedsiębiorstwa. Budowanie konkurencyjności przedsiębiorstwa w warunkach globalizacji. Toruń: TNOiK.
- Sundararajan, A. (2016). The sharing economy. The end of employment and the rise of crowd-based capitalism. Cambridge, Massachusetts, London: The MIT Press.
- Toroń, M., & Wiese, K. (2017). Aplikacja UBER lub jak ująć sharing economy w istniejące ramy prawne. Internetowy Kwartalnik Antymonopolowy i Regulacyjny, 5(6), 8-27. DOI: 10.7172/2299-5749.IKAR.5.6.1
- Wagner, T., Kuhndt, M., Lagomarsino, J., & Mattar, H. (2015). Listening to Sharing Economy Initiatives. Retrieved from https://www.scp-centre.org/wp-content/uploads/2016/05/Listening_to_Sharing_Economy_Initiatives.pdf
- Wosskow, D. (2014). Unlocking the sharing economy. An independent review. Retrieved from https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/378291/bis-14-1227-unlocking-the-sharing-economy-an-independent-review.pdf
- Zervas, G., Proserpio, D., & Byers, J. (2015). A First Look at Online Reputation on Airbnb, Where Every Stay Is Above Average. Retrieved from https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2554500
Add to: Del.icio.us Facebook Wykop Twitter.com Blip.pl Digg.com
AUTHOR |
About the article
DOI: https://doi.org/10.15219/em80.1423
The article is in the printed version on pages 51-57.
How to cite
Godlewska, M. (2019). Competition Mechanisms in the Sharing Economy. e-mentor, 3(80), 51-57. DOI: 10.15219/em80.1423
References
1 The relevant literature is divided on whether UberX and Airbnb are part of the sharing economy (see also Slee, 2015; Meleen &Frenken, 2015; Sundararajan, 2016).
2 The study of the competition methods used by online platforms utilized a methodology as presented in Konecki, 2018; Corbin & Strauss, 1990; Glaser&Strauss, 1967.
3 Competition as defined in Stankiewicz (2005, p. 18).
4 Price competition (PC) and non-price competition (NC).
5 Price competition (PC) and non-price competition (NC).
6 For-profit (FP) and Non-profit (NP).
7 Recipients (R) and Providers (P).
8 Economic advantage (E), e.g. participating in costs, additional income or flexible terms of employment; Social advantage (S), e.g. meeting new people; Epistemic advantage (EP), e.g. new experiences.
9 Couchsurfing is a platform where hosts make their couches available for free to guests of their choosing.